• Home

Royal Flamingo Casino

 
  1. A reputable online casino should be licensed and regulated by an independent governing body. This means their games are regularly inspected Royal Flamingo Casino to ensure they give players fair games.
  2. Royal Flamingo Casino is a trustworthy suite that features a massive collection of games from top providers. With our review, you can get started with an appealing welcome bonus and will be able to take advantage of ongoing offers to boost account balances.
  1. Flamingo Casino City
  2. Royal Flamingo Villas
  3. Royal Flamingo Casino No Deposit Bonus
  4. Royal Club Casino
1 vote (16.66%)
No votes (0%)
3 votes (50%)
No votes (0%)
No votes (0%)
No votes (0%)
No votes (0%)
No votes (0%)
1 vote (16.66%)
1 vote (16.66%)

6 members have voted

Wizard
Administrator
There is a beach one mile long with people distributed uniformly along the mile. When anyone on the beach gets hungry, he goes to the nearest hot dog stand.
There are three vendors who are all perfect logicians. Each wishes to maximize his own sales. They don't trust each other, so no colluding.
It is known that A will arrive first, then B, and then C. B and C will note the locations of the vendors who arrived before them and locate their stand accordingly.

Royal Flamingo Casino was created in 2013, with its main purpose being to provide the most secure and fair casino games. The casino is regulated under the jurisdiction of Curacao. It uses the most advanced SSL protocol, which ensures the protection and security of players personal and sensitive information. Flamingo Las Vegas (formerly The Fabulous Flamingo and Flamingo Hilton Las Vegas) is a casino hotel on the Las Vegas Strip in Paradise, Nevada. It is owned and operated by Caesars Entertainment. The property includes a 72,299 square-foot casino along with 3,460 hotel rooms.


Where should A set up his stand?
It's not whether you win or lose; it's whether or not you had a good bet.

Flamingo Casino City

rudeboyoi
I don't think this is the answer you're looking for but this reminded me of an interesting video on the economics of why competitors group close together. And they use a beach as an example.
https://youtu.be/jILgxeNBK_8
If A picks the middle though the most he is going to end up with is only 25% while B and C end up with 37.5%.
beachbumbabs
Administrator
I think the one assumption is that all are perfect logicians. So A should set up 34% (or 33.4, or 33.34, as far as you want to run it out, but just slightly more than 1/3) of the way from the end of the beach in either direction.
If B sets up 35% from the opposite side or more, that forces C to set up to the far end of him, right next to him, so B can set up no closer to the middle than 33%.
C will then set up at the mid-point between them to get both sides rather than an end run, as that will be slightly more advantageous to him than setting up on either end. So A will get the 'most' by a very slight amount, but it will be the most.
Not sure how much room you take up for the actual width of the stand, but it could matter in measuring 'most' once all 3 are there.
If the House lost every hand, they wouldn't deal the game.
unJon
So if A goes in the middle, B will set up either just to the left or right of him and C just on the other side, leaving A with territory approaching 0. So A needs to go to one side to make B and C move away from him towards the larger territory. This is definitely an economic problem I’ve solved in college (I forget the name, but it’s different if the oligopolies move sequentially or simultaneously.
Let’s say A sets up to the left of center (closer to 0). B will want to make C indifferent about moving just to the left or right of him So B sets up at a distance where 1-B = 0.5(B-A). That’s because C captures all the territory between B and the 1 mile mark and only half of the territory between B and C. Oh but there should also be a boundary condition where 1-B > A or else B would move slightly to the left of A to steal all of that territory between 0 and A. Since A is going to want to make B indifferent about moving to the left and right of him, the boundary condition yields 1-B=A.
So we have two equations and two unknowns.
Manipulating the first equation gets to:
A = 3B - 2
Plug into above for B = 1-A
A = 3(1 - A) - 2
A = 3 - 3A - 2
4A = 1
A = 1/4
I think that works. B then sets up at 3/4. And C is indifferent between just to the right of B, anywhere between A and B or just to the left of A.
Hmm I guess there was another hidden boundary condition where C could cut off A, which would happen if A moved to the right of 1/4.
ETA: I guess A is risking C taking the territory just to his left, which would be bad, so I think technically A should move a “smidge” to the left of 1/4 so that C is disincentivized to do that. Then B should move a smidge to the right of 3/4, making C want to land in the middle of A and B.
The race is not always to the swift, nor the battle to the strong; but that is the way to bet.
unJon
I think the one assumption is that all are perfect logicians. So A should set up 34% (or 33.4, or 33.34, as far as you want to run it out, but just slightly more than 1/3) of the way from the end of the beach in either direction.
If B sets up 35% from the opposite side or more, that forces C to set up to the far end of him, right next to him, so B can set up no closer to the middle than 33%.
C will then set up at the mid-point between them to get both sides rather than an end run, as that will be slightly more advantageous to him than setting up on either end. So A will get the 'most' by a very slight amount, but it will be the most.
Not sure how much room you take up for the actual width of the stand, but it could matter in measuring 'most' once all 3 are there.
Babs, I think
At A=1/3 and B=2/3 then C does best avoiding the middle (where he only gets half of the middle so 1/6) and taking one of the sides, which screws over A, since B will make his side slightly smaller than As
.
The race is not always to the swift, nor the battle to the strong; but that is the way to bet.
beachbumbabs
Administrator
Quote: beachbumbabs
I think the one assumption is that all are perfect logicians. So A should set up 34% (or 33.4, or 33.34, as far as you want to run it out, but just slightly more than 1/3) of the way from the end of the beach in either direction.
If B sets up 35% from the opposite side or more, that forces C to set up to the far end of him, right next to him, so B can set up no closer to the middle than 33%.
C will then set up at the mid-point between them to get both sides rather than an end run, as that will be slightly more advantageous to him than setting up on either end. So A will get the 'most' by a very slight amount, but it will be the most.
Not sure how much room you take up for the actual width of the stand, but it could matter in measuring 'most' once all 3 are there.
Babs, I think
At A=1/3 and B=2/3 then C does best avoiding the middle (where he only gets half of the middle so 1/6) and taking one of the sides, which screws over A, since B will make his side slightly smaller than As
.
That makes sense, thanks!
If the House lost every hand, they wouldn't deal the game.
Wizard
Administrator
Royal Flamingo Casino
So if A goes in the middle, B will set up either just to the left or right of him and C just on the other side, leaving A with territory approaching 0. So A needs to go to one side to make B and C move away from him towards the larger territory. This is definitely an economic problem I’ve solved in college (I forget the name, but it’s different if the oligopolies move sequentially or simultaneously.
Let’s say A sets up to the left of center (closer to 0). B will want to make C indifferent about moving just to the left or right of him So B sets up at a distance where 1-B = 0.5(B-A). That’s because C captures all the territory between B and the 1 mile mark and only half of the territory between B and C. Oh but there should also be a boundary condition where 1-B > A or else B would move slightly to the left of A to steal all of that territory between 0 and A. Since A is going to want to make B indifferent about moving to the left and right of him, the boundary condition yields 1-B=A.
So we have two equations and two unknowns.
Manipulating the first equation gets to:
A = 3B - 2
Plug into above for B = 1-A
A = 3(1 - A) - 2
A = 3 - 3A - 2
4A = 1
A = 1/4
I think that works. B then sets up at 3/4. And C is indifferent between just to the right of B, anywhere between A and B or just to the left of A.
Hmm I guess there was another hidden boundary condition where C could cut off A, which would happen if A moved to the right of 1/4.
ETA: I guess A is risking C taking the territory just to his left, which would be bad, so I think technically A should move a “smidge” to the left of 1/4 so that C is disincentivized to do that. Then B should move a smidge to the right of 3/4, making C want to land in the middle of A and B.

Yes, this is what I get too, and for the same reasons. Congratulations! I now owe you two beers.
However, I think I'm going to put you on the list of math wizards who are on a 24-hour delay for future problems, to give others a chance.

General comment #1 -- If one of the vendors is indifferent between multiple locations, you may assume he picks randomly.
General comment #2 -- Once a vendor picks a spot, he must stay there the rest of the day.
It's not whether you win or lose; it's whether or not you had a good bet.
Wizard
Administrator
I don't think this is the answer you're looking for but this reminded me of an interesting video on the economics of why competitors group close together. And they use a beach as an example.
https://youtu.be/jILgxeNBK_8
If A picks the middle though the most he is going to end up with is only 25% while B and C end up with 37.5%.

Yes, this a classic game theory exercise. However, it a process of many steps. I contend if the three vendors were allowed to relocate, then they would all end up exactly at the half way point, forcing customers to pick a vendor arbitrarily.
I probably should have made a comment that the cart had to remain in the same place once the location was chosen for the rest of the day.

Royal Flamingo Villas

It's not whether you win or lose; it's whether or not you had a good bet.
EvenBob
It's raining, I would call Uber Eats and
set up tomorrow.
'It's not enough to succeed, your friends must fail.' Gore Vidal
unJon
Quote: unJon
So if A goes in the middle, B will set up either just to the left or right of him and C just on the other side, leaving A with territory approaching 0. So A needs to go to one side to make B and C move away from him towards the larger territory. This is definitely an economic problem I’ve solved in college (I forget the name, but it’s different if the oligopolies move sequentially or simultaneously.
Let’s say A sets up to the left of center (closer to 0). B will want to make C indifferent about moving just to the left or right of him So B sets up at a distance where 1-B = 0.5(B-A). That’s because C captures all the territory between B and the 1 mile mark and only half of the territory between B and C. Oh but there should also be a boundary condition where 1-B > A or else B would move slightly to the left of A to steal all of that territory between 0 and A. Since A is going to want to make B indifferent about moving to the left and right of him, the boundary condition yields 1-B=A.
So we have two equations and two unknowns.
Manipulating the first equation gets to:
A = 3B - 2
Plug into above for B = 1-A
A = 3(1 - A) - 2
A = 3 - 3A - 2
4A = 1
A = 1/4
I think that works. B then sets up at 3/4. And C is indifferent between just to the right of B, anywhere between A and B or just to the left of A.
Hmm I guess there was another hidden boundary condition where C could cut off A, which would happen if A moved to the right of 1/4.
ETA: I guess A is risking C taking the territory just to his left, which would be bad, so I think technically A should move a “smidge” to the left of 1/4 so that C is disincentivized to do that. Then B should move a smidge to the right of 3/4, making C want to land in the middle of A and B.

That compliment (however unfounded) is worth at least the two beers. Thanks, Wizard!

Royal Flamingo Casino No Deposit Bonus

Yes, this is what I get too, and for the same reasons. Congratulations! I now owe you two beers.
However, I think I'm going to put you on the list of math wizards who are on a 24-hour delay for future problems, to give others a chance.

Royal Club Casino

General comment #1 -- If one of the vendors is indifferent between multiple locations, you may assume he picks randomly.
General comment #2 -- Once a vendor picks a spot, he must stay there the rest of the day.
Thanks, Wizard! That compliment (however unfounded) is worth at least two beers. (Side note: it’s three beers)
The race is not always to the swift, nor the battle to the strong; but that is the way to bet.
Why You Should Book With Us Directly!
Best Rate: It is simple, when you book with us you are guaranteed the best rate for the Villa that fits your needs. We offer 40 villas to choose from.
Personalize the Booking: Receive our own confirmation emails which offer extensive personalization and tracking so that we can connect with you on a personal level. Deal directly throughout the transaction.
Pre-check-in instructions prior to your stay for a worry free, contactless arrival!

Personalized Service: When you book by phone or email with us you will be talking with a professional, on-site, front desk person who knows our property inside out. They will explain villa types, booking options, resort policies and answer those questions for you that only an on property person can handle without confusion.
No Hidden Charges: Our published rate is what you pay. Nothing more.

— Innovative Disinfection Technologies: RFV uses electrostatically charged disinfecting mist (among other solutions) to sanitize surfaces and objects. This technology uses the “highest classification of disinfectants recommended by the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention and World Health Organization.”

Nothing like it on the whole Gold Coast!
TROPICAL PARADISE